欢迎来到沃文网! | 帮助中心 分享知识,传播智慧!
沃文网
全部分类
  • 教学课件>
  • 医学资料>
  • 技术资料>
  • 学术论文>
  • 资格考试>
  • 建筑施工>
  • 实用文档>
  • 其他资料>
  • ImageVerifierCode 换一换
    首页 沃文网 > 资源分类 > DOC文档下载
    分享到微信 分享到微博 分享到QQ空间

    金融学外文翻译银行信贷标准.doc

    • 资源ID:824214       资源大小:73.50KB        全文页数:17页
    • 资源格式: DOC        下载积分:10积分
    快捷下载 游客一键下载
    账号登录下载
    微信登录下载
    三方登录下载: QQ登录 微博登录
    二维码
    微信扫一扫登录
    下载资源需要10积分
    邮箱/手机:
    温馨提示:
    快捷下载时,用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)。
    如填写123,账号就是123,密码也是123。
    支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
    验证码:   换一换

    加入VIP,下载更划算!
     
    账号:
    密码:
    验证码:   换一换
      忘记密码?
        
    友情提示
    2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
    3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
    4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。
    5、试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓。

    金融学外文翻译银行信贷标准.doc

    1、原文 Bank Credit Standards By Mitchell BerlinBankers and the business press often speak of cycles in bank credit standards, periods in which banks lending standards are too lax, followed by periods in which standards are too stringent. In this view, bank lending policies tend to amplify fluctuations i

    2、n GDP;easy money during the upturn sows the seeds of tight money episodes in the downturn. But this pattern is also consistent with variations in bank lending driven by changes in borrowers default risk over the business cycle or changes in the demand for loans, which rises and falls with GDP. To ma

    3、ke sense of the idea of a lending cycle, we must uncover a systematic reason for banks to make unprofitable loans in an upturn and to forgot profitable loans in a downturn. I emphasize that the tendency must be systematic to distinguish the idea of a credit cycle from the truism that loans made near

    4、 the peak of an expansion are more likely to go bad simply because bankers (just like economists and other businessmen) have difficulties predicting downturns. What is the evidence for an independent effect for changing bank lending standards that is, a systematic reason why banks might be too lax o

    5、r too stringent? And what factors might explain this type of behavior? Economists have proposed a number of plausible models of a bank lending cycle, emphasizing changes in bank capital, competition, or herding behavior. To date, only the channel relating changes in bank capital to lending standards

    6、 has firm empirical support.The available evidence is too weak to give us much confidence in assigning an important role for other theories of bank lending standards. WHAT ARE CREDIT STANDARDS? It is helpful to be a little clearer about what we mean by a change in bank credit standards. Lets begin w

    7、ith a straightforward prescription from investment theory: A profitmaximizing bank should make any loan with a positive net present value (NPV). The NPV of a loan is just the sum of discounted future repayments (principal plus interest) on the loan minus the loan amount. Future repayments must be di

    8、scounted for two different reasons: First, $10 in the bank now is worth more than $10 paid a year from now. After all, the bank could receive a years interest by purchasing Treasury bills on the $10 paid back tomorrow. Second, the bank recognizes that the borrower may default in the future, so the b

    9、ank may never receive some future payments. The firm may have a healthy balance sheet at the time the loan is made; a year from now, the borrowing firm may suffer financial setbacks and may be unable to pay back its loan. Using this framework, we can define a change in bank credit standards as a cha

    10、nge in a banks loangranting decisions for some reason other than a change in the NPV of the loan. We can define a credit cycle as a systematic tendency to fund negative NPV loans during an expansion and a systematic tendency to reject positive NPV loans during a contraction. Since bankslending decis

    11、ions also involve the pricing and design of loan contracts, a credit cycle might also take the form of a systematic tendency to relax or tighten loan terms by more than would be justified by changes in borrower risk. Conceptually, it is not too difficult to define a credit cycle. Empirically, it may

    12、 be much harder to tell whether one has occurred. For example, think about some of the things that happen in an economic downturn. As economic conditions become more difficult, more firms experience economic difficulties and the probability that a firm will default increases. This reduces the NPV of

    13、 a given stream of repayments and would probably induce the bank to raise the loan rate, impose new contractual restrictions, or refuse to make the loan at all. While these actions might be interpreted as a tightening of standards by an outside observer or by an aggrieved borrower, credit standards

    14、havent changed according to our definition. Figures 1a and 1b illustrate the distinction between the effects of a tightening of credit standards and the effects of an increase in credit risk. Figure 1a shows a probability distribution of loan applicants NPVs. The profit-maximizing rule for a bank is

    15、 to make a loan as long as its NPV is positive (the sum of the shaded regions). If the bank tightens its credit standards, for example, making only loans with an NPV greater than $A, the bank will make a smaller number of loans (just the darker region). Figure 1b illustrates the effects of a downtur

    16、n: Loans become riskier and the distribution of NPVs shifts to the left. But this figure shows a bank that retains the profit-maximizing rule. Note that the number of loans made falls in this case also (from the sum of the shaded regions to just the darker region). Slightly more subtly, in a downtur

    17、n many loans often go bad at once. Typically, a bank will charge a borrower a higher loan rate if the borrower is likely to default at the same time as other borrowers in a banks portfolio default. To see this, consider a Detroit bank that has a portfolio with a high concentration of loans to auto p

    18、arts suppliers. This bank is evaluating two prospective loans with identical probabilities of default. One of the loans is to an auto parts supplier, and the other is to a department store. Even though the probability of default is identical for both projects, the bank will not charge the same defau

    19、lt risk premium to both. Instead, the bank will charge a higher risk premium for the loan to the auto parts supplier because its performance is more highly correlated with the rest of the banks portfolio. Taking this idea a step further, economists have found that firms defaults tend to be correlate

    20、d.Thus, we should not be surprised that a bank would demand a higher premium for default risk in a downturn as compensation for the higher probability that many loans will go bad at the same time. Although the bank has charged borrowers a higher price for bearing risk, this should not be viewed as a

    21、 change in credit standards. In an economic downturn, nonfinancial firms also cut back on investments in plant and equipment and inventories, and, in turn, they cut back on borrowing. A decline in the demand for loans should certainly not be viewed as a change in bank credit standards. We can see th

    22、e empirical challenge in identifying an independent effect for lending standards on the quantity of loans. Consider an economic downturn. In a downturn, default risk increases, risks become more correlated, and the demand for loans declines. None of these factors reflects a change in lending standar

    23、ds, but all lead to a decline in the quantity of loans made. To uncover a lending cycle, the researcher must find some way todisentangle the effects of changing lending standards from these other effects. THE BROAD FACTS Economists have documented a number of empirical observations that are broadly

    24、consistent with the existence of a lending cycle.The first empirical observation is that declines in bank capital are associated with declines in bank lending. Ben Bernanke and Cara Lown (among many others) have found evidence that large negative shocks to bank capital (such as those experienced by

    25、banks in New England at the end of the 1980s )are associated with declines in bank lending. The relationship between capital and lending is a robust empirical finding, but since the weak economic conditions associated with a decline in bank capital are also associated with higher default risk, more

    26、correlated risks, and a decline in loan demand, economists have had to be ingenious in providing compelling evidence for the capital channel (as I discuss in the next section). A second observation is the well-documented flight to quality during economic downturns. For example, William Lang and Leon

    27、ard Nakamura show that bank portfolios shift from high- to low-risk loans during a downturn; specifically, they show that bank portfolios shift away from loans made above the prime rate. Their finding is consistent with evidence that during a downturn, banks systematically shift their portfolios tow

    28、ard larger borrowers and toward borrowers with pre-existing loan commitments.While these studies shed light on the ways that bank lending may amplify negative economic shocks, the observed portfolio shifts may simply reflect a rise in default risk during an economic downturn, rather than an independ

    29、ent role for lending standards, according to our definition. With a rise in default risk, some borrowers are shut out of public debt markets and shift toward bank borrowing, while bank portfolios shift toward lower risk borrowers. A third observation is that loan terms vary systematically over the b

    30、usiness cycle in a way that may amplify economic fluctuations. Patrick Asea and Asa Blomberg find that commercial loan markups (the spread between the loan rate and the rate on a riskless Treasury security) fall continuously right up to the beginning of a recession. Their interpretation of this find

    31、ing is that credit standards are excessively easy at the end of an expansion, sowing the seeds of future portfolio problems. Jianping Mei and Anthony Saunders provide evidence of trendchasing behavior by banks. They find that banks increase real estate lending when past real estate returns are high,

    32、 but that bank real estate investments are unprofitable, on average. These results are consistent with a systematic tendency for excessively lax credit standards during an expansion, and they may also be evidence of a tendency for banks to invest in a herd-like manner. However, the evidence from com

    33、mercial lending and real estate lending markets may simply mean that banks have difficulty predicting a downturn (just like everyone else). Thus, banks may continue lending strongly even as the downturn begins. The most direct evidence for a direct role for bank credit standards comes from survey re

    34、sults. Cara Lown and Donald Morgan analyze the Federal Reserve Boards Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey, in which bankers are asked periodically whether they changed their credit standards in the previous three months. They are also asked to explain how their standards changed, e.g., changes in col

    35、lateral requirements, covenants, and loan markups, as well as the underlying reasons for any change. Using a statistical analysis called a vector autoregression (VAR), Lown and Morgan find that changes in credit standards (as measured by survey responses) have a significant effect on both the quanti

    36、ty of bank loans and GDP.Interestingly, changes in GDP do not have a significant effect on lending standards, suggesting an independent role for credit standards. While this is perhaps the most convincing evidence that changes in bank credit standards have an independent effect, Lown and Morgan do n

    37、ot provide evidence that banks systematically choose excessively lax or risky lending standards. To sum up, there is survey evidence of an independent role for bank credit standards, and a number of empirical observations are broadly consistent with the existence of a lending cycle. Making further p

    38、rogress requires a theoretical framework that would permit us to disentangle the various effects on banks lending behavior. CAPITAL CONSTRAINTS LEAD BANKS TO TIGHTEN STANDARDS Bank Lending Is Limited by Bank Capital. A wide range of models show that a firms investments in plant, equipment, and inven

    39、tories are limited by the firms capital, i.e., the funds committed by the firms owners. A bank is just a particular type of firm, but instead of investment in goods and machines, its main investments are loans. While the precise link between capital and investment differs from model to model, the el

    40、ement common to all of them is that agency problems limit firms access to outside funding. In our context, the term “agency problem” refers to a conflict of interest between a firms insiders owners and top managers, who are influential in a firms decision-making and outside investors depositors, bon

    41、dholders, and perhaps small stockholders, who control only their willingness to provide funds. For example, in Bengt Holmstrom and Jean Tiroles model, the banks insiders have a choice between carefully monitoring borrowers and avoiding the costs of monitoring. A carefully monitored loan has low risk

    42、 and positive NPV; a loan that is not monitored has a high risk of default and a negative NPV. The underlying agency problem is that a firms insiders will forgo monitoring and make high-risk loans unless they receive a sufficiently large share of the total profits.But providing insiders with incenti

    43、ves to monitor limits the share of the returns left over for outside investors, who will refuse to provide funds unless their own expected rate of return is adequate. The role of bank capital in all this is that a firms insiders have a stronger incentive to engage in costly monitoring of loans when

    44、more of their own funds are at risk, i.e., when bank capital is higher. Outside investors will refuse to provide funds to banks that are not well-capitalized.In Holmstrom and Tiroles model, a bank with insufficient capital may be unable to convince outside investors to fund loans that would have pos

    45、itive NPV if the bank could make a credible guarantee to monitor. When Bank Capital Falls, Banks Tighten Lending Standards. Loan losses are countercyclical; in particular, in an economic downturn, more borrowers default and loan losses increase (Figure 2). Higher loan losses reduce bank capital, and

    46、 the availability of outside financing also decreases. In turn, banks may be forced to forgo loans with positive NPV (if properly monitored); that is, banks will have excessively tight lending standards. Most models that focus on the link between capital and the availability of outside funds focus o

    47、n economic capital, but similar limits on lending arise if regulators limit bank lending when loan losses press banks against regulatory capital requirements. Note that this model predicts that capital shortages will restrict lending but it doesnt predict that banks would ever have excessively lax c

    48、redit standards. That is, according to Holmstrom and Tirole, banks will forgo positive NPV loans when access to outside funds is restricted because their capital is low, but high bank capital doesnt increase the likelihood that a bank will make a negative NPV loan. Empirical Evidence for the Capital

    49、 Channel. A large empirical literature documents the effect of negative shocks to banks capital on bank lending. In particular, a number of studies of the 1990-92 credit crunch in the U.S. show that declines in bank capital were systematically associated with declines in bank lending, consistent with the statements of bankers, borrowers, and bank re


    注意事项

    本文(金融学外文翻译银行信贷标准.doc)为本站会员(精***)主动上传,沃文网仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知沃文网(点击联系客服),我们立即给予删除!




    关于我们 - 网站声明 - 网站地图 - 资源地图 - 友情链接 - 网站客服点击这里,给沃文网发消息,QQ:2622162128 - 联系我们

    版权声明:以上文章中所选用的图片及文字来源于网络以及用户投稿,由于未联系到知识产权人或未发现有关知识产权的登记,如有知识产权人并不愿意我们使用,如有侵权请立即联系:2622162128@qq.com ,我们立即下架或删除。

    Copyright© 2022-2024 www.wodocx.com ,All Rights Reserved |陕ICP备19002583号-1

    陕公网安备 61072602000132号     违法和不良信息举报:0916-4228922