资本结构和债务结构【外文翻译】.doc
《资本结构和债务结构【外文翻译】.doc》由会员分享,可在线阅读,更多相关《资本结构和债务结构【外文翻译】.doc(13页珍藏版)》请在沃文网上搜索。
1、外 文 翻 译原文:Capital Structure and Debt StructureIn this study, we provide a number of new insights into capital structure decisions by recognizing that firms simultaneously use different types, sources, and priorities of debt. These insights are based on a novel data set that records the type, source,
2、 and priority of every balance sheet debt instrument for a large sample of rated public firms. The data are collected directly from financial footnotes in firms annual 10-K filings and supplemented with information on pricing and covenants from three origination based datasets: Reuters LPCs Dealscan
3、, Mergents Fixed Income Securities Database, and Thomsons SDC Platinum. To our knowledge, this data set is one of the most comprehensive sources of information on the debt structure of a sample of public firms: It contains the detailed composition of the stock of corporate debt on the balance sheet,
4、 which goes far beyond what is available from origination-based datasets alone.We begin by showing the importance of recognizing debt heterogeneity in capital structure studies. We classify debt into bank debt, straight bond debt, convertible bond debt, program debt (such as commercial paper), mortg
5、age debt, and all other debt. For almost 70% of firm-year observations in our sample, balance sheet debt comprises significant amounts of at least two of these types. Even more striking is the fact that 25% of the observations in our sample experience no significant one-year change in their total de
6、bt but significantly adjust the underlying composition of their debt. Studies that treat corporate debt as uniform have ignored this heterogeneity, presumably in the interest of building more tractable theory models or due to a previous lack of data.In this section, we motivate our empirical analysi
7、s of the relation between debt structure and credit quality by examining hypotheses from the theoretical literature on debt composition and priority.The first group of theories hypothesizes that firms should move from bank debt to non-bank debt as credit quality improves (Diamond, 1991; Chemmamur an
8、d Fulghieri, 1994; Boot and Thakor, 1997;Bolton and Freixas, 2000). The seminal article is Diamonds (1991b) model of reputation acquisition. In his model, firms graduate from bank debt to arms length debt by establishing a reputation for high earnings. More specifically, the main variable that gener
9、ates cross-sectional predictions is the ex-ante probability that a firm is a bad type with a bad project; this ex-ante probability is updated over periods based on earnings performance, and is interpreted as a credit rating. Bad firms have a lower history of earnings, and a higher probability of sel
10、ecting a bad project in the future. High quality firms borrow directly from arms length lenders and avoid additional costs of bank debt associated with monitoring,medium-quality firms borrow from banks that provide incentives from monitoring, and the lowest qualityfirms are rationed.The model by Bol
11、ton and Freixas (2000) explores the optimal mix of bonds, bank debt, and equity. The key distinction between bonds and bank debt is the monitoring ability of banks. If current returns are low and default is pending, banks can investigate the borrowers future profitability, whereas bond holders alway
12、s liquidate the borrower. In their model, high quality firms do not value the ability of banks to investigate, and therefore rely primarily on arms length debt. Lower quality borrowers value theability to investigate by the bank, and thus rely more heavily on bank financing.Two main hypotheses emerg
13、e from this kind of model. First, the lender with monitoring duties (the bank) should be the most senior in the capital structure. The intuition is as follows: a banks incentive to monitor is maximized when the bank appropriates the full return from its monitoring effort. In the presence of senior o
14、r pari passu non-monitoring lenders, the bank is forced to share the return to monitoring with other creditors, which reduces the banks incentive to monitor.Second, the presence of junior non-bank creditors enhances the senior banks incentive tomonitor. This result follows from the somewhat counteri
15、ntuitive argument that a bank has a strongerincentive to monitor if its claim is smaller. Park (2000) describes this intuition as follows: if the project continues, an impaired senior lender will get less than a sole lender simply because his claim is smaller. On the other hand, if the project is li
16、quidated, an impaired senior lender will get the same amount as a sole lender, the liquidation value. Given its lower value in the going concern, a bank with a smaller claim actually has a stronger incentive to monitor and liquidate the firm. The presence of junior debt reduces the size of the banks
17、 claim, which increases the amount of socially beneficial monitoring.The intuition of this latter result is evident if one considers a bank creditor with a claim that represents a very large fraction of the borrowers capital structure. In such a situation, the bank has less of an incentive to liquid
18、ate a risky borrower, given that the banks large claim benefits relatively more from risk-taking than a smaller claim. In other words, a large bank claim is more “equity-like” than a small bank claim given its upside potential. As a result, reducing the size of the senior bank claim by addingjunior
19、debt improves the banks incentive to detect risk-shifting. Alternatively, by holding a small stake in the firm, bank lenders are able to credibly threaten borrowers with liquidation, which makes their monitoring more powerful in reducing managerial value-decreasing behavior.There are at least two wa
20、ys, however, in which the existing theories do not map into our empirical design. First, theories such as Diamond (1993), Besanko and Kanatas (1993), and Park (2000) derive a priority structure as the optimal contract under incentive conflicts, but they do not explicitly derive the comparative stati
21、c of how optimal priority structure should vary across a continuum of incentive conflict severity. A thought experiment close to this is provided by DeMarzo and Fishman (2007), who do examine the comparative statics of debt structure with respect to liquidation values,managerial patience, and manage
22、rial private benefits. However, their predictions are about the mix between long-term debt and lines of credit, rather than priority structure per se.Second, with the exception of DeMarzo and Fishman (2007) and some other recent dynamic contracting work, these theories are static in nature, and ther
23、efore do not predict how debt structure should change with respect to the evolution of stochastic cash flows. In this sense, the theory is more relevant for our random sample cross-sectional results more than our panel results on fallen angels.Indeed, Diamond (1993), Besanko and Kanatas (1993), and
24、Park (2000) are ex-ante models in which moral hazard explains the existence of priority structure; however, they do not consider dynamic deterioration in the firms credit quality. In DeMarzo and Fishman (2007), agents draw down on credit lines when cash flows are insufficient to pay debt coupons. Ho
- 1.请仔细阅读文档,确保文档完整性,对于不预览、不比对内容而直接下载带来的问题本站不予受理。
- 2.下载的文档,不会出现我们的网址水印。
- 3、该文档所得收入(下载+内容+预览)归上传者、原创作者;如果您是本文档原作者,请点此认领!既往收益都归您。
下载文档到电脑,查找使用更方便
20 积分
下载 | 加入VIP,下载更划算! |
- 配套讲稿:
如PPT文件的首页显示word图标,表示该PPT已包含配套word讲稿。双击word图标可打开word文档。
- 特殊限制:
部分文档作品中含有的国旗、国徽等图片,仅作为作品整体效果示例展示,禁止商用。设计者仅对作品中独创性部分享有著作权。
- 关 键 词:
- 外文翻译 资本 结构 债务 外文 翻译